Learn how framing affects betting

ATP

If World No. 1 Novak Djokovic was playing World No. 60 Paul-Henri Mathieu in a five set Grand Slam tournament, what respective odds would you expect for this game? How  about Djokovic 1.72, Mathieu 2.40? Does that seem realistic?

 

If these odds appear a bit off, it’s probably because you typically wouldn’t give Djokovic a slim 58% chance of winning and the Frenchman a somewhat generous 42%  chance. These are real odds, however, but just not for the match outcome.

Instead, these are the odds of winning each point, accurate for this pair’s encounter in the first round of 2013 Australian Open, which Djokovic went on to win (6-2,  6-4, 7-5).

 

Let’s break the numbers down. The game featured 163 points, of which Djokovic won 95 and Mathieu 68. From this we can produce a probability per point of 95/163 for  Djokovic and 68/163 for his opponent. The actual odds for the entire match were entirely different at:

 

Djokovic 1.01

Mathieu 41.00

 

Both sets of odds are accurate, but are looking at the game from entirely different perspectives or “frames”: the narrow frame (one point) vs. the broad frame (the  entire match).

 

People struggle to reconcile the differing probabilities of the two perspectives – even though they are for the same event – and this can have significant  consequences, especially in live tennis betting.

 

Live betting effectively looks at the game point-by-point, and at the scale Mathieu truly does have a 42% success rate. This can lead bettors to overstate his overall  chance, however, especially if they get caught up with the emotion of the crowd and the commentators.

 

A 42% win percentage per point, extrapolated over all 163 points, however,  translates to a chance of 41.00 for overall success as suggested by the odds (which  suggests that if the pair played 40 times the Frenchman would win once).

 

Framing: a market for success

 

The phenomenon of framing bias has been documented by decision-making theorists and is seen where someone is averse to an isolated gamble, because subjective reason  believes it to be risky despite the expected value being positive. A famous example is:

 

Would you take the following gamble on a single coin toss?

 

Heads loses you $100, tails wins you $200

 

The majority of people, displaying common risk aversion, reject the offer, focusing on the potential loss in the single toss scenario, even though the Expected Value,  and therefore the probability of making money, is $50:

 

Objective Expected Value = (0.5*200)-(0.5*100) = $50

 

The academic reasoning for this is that people tend to feel the loss of $1 twice as much as the gain of the same amount. Applying this factor of two for losses, the  Expected Value for the single gamble to zero and hence it is rejected:

 

Loss Averse Expected Value = (0.5*200)-(0.5*100*2) = $0

 

By expanding our framing to more than a one-off, however, we can get a better understanding of how much we’re likely to win or lose. Compare this slightly larger frame  of two coin tosses:

 

Two tosses Heads lose $100 – Tails win $200

 

25% lose $200; 50% win $100; 25% win $400. The EV is $100

 

As above, but with losses doubled due to loss aversion:

 

25% lose $400; 50% win $100; 25% win $400 – EV is $50

 

Even with a heightened fear of loss, the Expected Value of two coin tosses is still more positive when viewed with a wider frame. Had you simply used the narrow-frame  to analysis the outcome of the two tosses, the opportunity to benefit would have been missed.

 

The loss adverse approach to this bet tends to remain consistent when considering multiple tosses, but as the cumulative odds of losing diminish with aggregate  gambles, loss aversion correspondingly diminishes.

 

If asked the same question based on a large number of tosses – a broader frame – people tend to be more comfortable with the gamble.

 

At 100 coin tosses, this bet (without the doubling) has an EV of $5,000 with only a 1 in 2,300 chance of losing any money and a 1 in 62,000 chance of losing $1,000.  However, by rejecting the isolated bet in the first instance – the narrow frame – you miss out.

 

Wider examples

 

The issues around framing are frequently observed in environments where frequency of data change is high, e.g. financial indexes. The more often you check the market –  and therefore the narrower the frame you take – the more likely you are to see noise rather than signal.

 

Nassim Nicholas Taleb summarises it neatly in his book Fooled By Randomness by illustrating that a portfolio of stocks with a 15% return and 10% volatility returns  surprisingly different chances of success at ever narrowing frames. If you were checking this portfolio every second the chance of success would be only 50.02% yet the  broad frame – over a year – is 93%.

 

The lesson to learn from narrow framing is try to see gambles in the aggregate form, thereby avoiding missing out on what are actually favourable outcomes that your  risk averse nature would otherwise intuitively reject.

 

French Open Live Betting – 1st Round Limits Raised to $1000

 

Pinnacle Sports has raised the limits for next game betting to $1,000 for the 1st round of the French Open, up from $250. These limits increase throughout the  tournament, so tennis live betting fans can now bet even more and stay in the action.

 

The French Open will also see the launch of live spread and live totals betting for tennis matches. These will be posted during changeovers with the money line.

 

Click here for the latest ATP French Open odds (and here for the WTA French Open odds).

 

(Source: Pinnacle)

 

Bet HERE

 

Viewed 1012 times

Comments and Feedback

There are no comments yet. Be the first to comment this article!

Register or log in to submit your comment.